South Africa

South Africa

A hitchhiker’s guide through the South African electricity system, PART TWO

A hitchhiker’s guide through the South African electricity system, PART TWO

It's going to get ugly here, so we, as South Africans, need to have much better understanding of our country's electricity system, Eskom, our consumption patterns and pricing, the cost of load-shedding and how we can, if indeed we can, escape from the precarious situation we find ourselves in these days. So we thought the best way to present it to you, dear traveller through the South African electrical space-time continuum, would be through this extensive hitchhiker's guide in six parts. Today, Part TWO: The nature of Eskom as a monopoly. Entire series conceptualised and written by DIRK DE VOS.

The nature of Eskom as a monopoly, representing, almost entirely, the South African electricity system

Recent history of operating below reserve margin:

  • 1974- 1977
  • 2007-2015 (to 2018?)

Load shedding

Recent biggest year-on-year tariff increases:

  • 1977 45%+ (real terms 21.9%)
  • 1982-1983 25% per annum (real terms3%)
  • 2008 27.5% (real terms 21%)
  • 2009 31.3% (real terms 25%)
  • 2010 24.8% (real terms 19%)
  • 2011 25.8% (real terms 21%)

History of Eskom debt/equity ratios

  • 1986: 2.93
  • 1998: 0.83
  • 2013: 1.84
  • 2014: 2.06

Discussion points

Eskom in its current format is a huge company and represents, for all practical purposes, our electricity system.

On the face of it, Eskom has supplied cheap and abundant electricity to South Africans for over a generation. This is not strictly true. As Professor Anton Eberhard points out, the cheap electricity emanated from previous investment splurges, very low coal prices, exemption from taxation and dividends, financing subsidies (including subsidised Reserve Bank forward cover), and previous loans funding over-capacity was largely amortised.

In the world of electricity utilities, Eskom is an extreme outlier. By generating capacity, it is the 5th or 6th biggest electricity utility in the world, but it operates in an economy that is only the 29th biggest by GDP. To some extent it is similar to French state-owned Électricité de France SA (EDF), but Eskom is even more dominant in its home market and EDF operates in several other jurisdictions in competition with other utilities receiving just a quarter of its total revenues from the French market.

While there is a lot of lamenting the poor planning and the way that Eskom has run its plant and grid, the government appears to be enthusiastic about central planning as an idea – but much less keen on doing actual planning. What we have is a reversion to the 2010 version of the Integrated Resource Plan (for electricity) which is now four years out of date, instead of using the 2013 update, which itself is over-optimistic on energy demand. As for the Integrated Energy Plan? A new one has not been seen for 10 years. But perhaps even the best plans are doomed to fail, because bouts of over- and under- investment by Eskom are an inevitable consequence of its monopoly.

Microeconomics, that part of the discipline which has emerged reasonably unscathed in recent times, can tell us a lot, with a considerable degree of accuracy, about the behaviour of monopolies under different circumstances. Any standard textbook on the subject gives the same predictions, but essentially the major difficulty with monopolies is the question of pricing. This is because a monopolist’s marginal revenue is always less than or equal to the price of the good sold (marginal revenue is the amount of revenue received for each additional unit of output). Getting the pricing right is hard to do.

Given that Eskom is such an outlier in the world of electricity utilities, surely part of fixing it would be to make it less of an outlier.

For electricity utilities, the common solution is to have the government or some type of regulator like NERSA determine prices, but the problem with setting the price is that monopolies, like Eskom, have a declining average total cost (put another way, marginal cost lies below average total cost). If the price is set at a level equal to the marginal cost, the monopoly will then incur losses and eventually become insolvent. Perhaps this describes neatly Eskom today. DM

Photo: Sinovuyo Bhungane (R), 9, studies using candle light during load shedding in Soweto February 3, 2015. REUTERS/Siphiwe Sibeko

Gallery

Please peer review 3 community comments before your comment can be posted

X

This article is free to read.

Sign up for free or sign in to continue reading.

Unlike our competitors, we don’t force you to pay to read the news but we do need your email address to make your experience better.


Nearly there! Create a password to finish signing up with us:

Please enter your password or get a sign in link if you’ve forgotten

Open Sesame! Thanks for signing up.

We would like our readers to start paying for Daily Maverick...

…but we are not going to force you to. Over 10 million users come to us each month for the news. We have not put it behind a paywall because the truth should not be a luxury.

Instead we ask our readers who can afford to contribute, even a small amount each month, to do so.

If you appreciate it and want to see us keep going then please consider contributing whatever you can.

Support Daily Maverick→
Payment options